piatok 27. augusta 2010

KOO: THE GLOBAL SLOWDOWN IS BECOMING MORE PRONOUNCED

The Pragmatic Capitalist:

Few people have a better grasp on the current economic predicament than Richard Koo. Koo is growing increasingly concerned about the state of the global economy and now believes the slowdown is becoming more pronounced:

“Signs of a slowdown in the global economy have become more prominent over the last two weeks. The deceleration in economic activity was reflected in the US jobs report and new unemployment claims, European industrial output, and Japanese consumer confidence. It was also reported on Monday that Japan’s inflation-adjusted GDP grew only 0.4% y-y in the Apr–Jun quarter, confirming that the recent slowdown actually began this spring.

This string of weak data led to a further correction in equities and pushed bond prices higher (and yields lower). Strong demand for government debt was underlined by yields ofsubstantially less than 3% for the 10-year Treasury note and less than 1% for the 10-year Japanese government bond.

In Ireland and some other countries in the eurozone, meanwhile, marked economic weakness fanned concerns about the future, leading investors to sell bonds and send interest rates higher.

In the currency markets, the narrowing yield differential between Japan and other nations prompted further buying of the yen, which set a new post-Lehman high of 84.72 against the US dollar.”

Koo is quick to note that the recovery we’ve seen since the Lehman collapse was primarily a mean reverting recovery that took us back to where we should have been in the first place had there been no Lehman related panic:

“That means that the rally that started about six months after the Lehman-inspired financial crisis was actually just a recovery from the Lehman crisis and not from the global housing bubble collapse in 2007.

The recovery from the financial crisis of 2008–09 was destined to run out of gas once economic activity rebounded to the (depressed) level where it would have been as a result of the balance sheet problems. I think that is what we are now observing in the US and Europe (Exhibit 1).”

koo1 KOO: THE GLOBAL SLOWDOWN IS BECOMING MORE PRONOUNCED


“In other words, the level of economic activity has returned to where it would have been if Lehman Brothers had not been allowed to fail.”

Koo is increasingly concerned that governments have already begun down the wrong path of austerity:

“But governments in the UK, Ireland and Spain have already changed course and are pursuing austerity policies. Even in the US, it remains to be seen whether the Bush tax cuts and the Obama economic stimulus can be extended.

The recovery from the 2008–09 financial crisis has now run its course, clearing the fog surrounding the balance sheet recession. But I suspect that more time and even weaker economic data will be necessary before people understand this and accept the need for further fiscal stimulus.”

In particular he is very worried about Europe and the actions taken by Trichet:

“Against this backdrop, I am particularly concerned by an opinion piece contributed to the 23 July Financial Times by ECB President Jean-Claude Trichet and titled, “Stimulate no more—it is now time for all to tighten.” In the article, Mr. Trichet argues that the economic recovery is already under way and that the fiscal stimulus administered by national governments over the past two years should be quickly withdrawn.

Mr. Trichet also argues that the series of fiscal stimulus packages unveiled by the G20 two years ago was actually a mistake and says it was unfortunate that some countries had administered stimulus without any need for it. Now, he says, it is time for all countries to pursue medium-term fiscal consolidation strategies.”

Koo believes Trichet is wrong because, like Bernanke, he has misunderstood the balance sheet recession. He believes Trichet is becoming “more German than the Germans” and is directly contributing to the recovery in that single nation while the periphery burns. Ultimately, he says Trichet is making the same mistakes as Bernanke – believing that austerity and monetary policy should rule the day. Richard Koo, who has been right thus far, says they still fail to understand the balance sheet recession. It looks to me like he’ll continue to be right.

streda 25. augusta 2010

The Trader’s Mindset

Charts Gone Wild:

I wrote this article on March 15, 2009. It’s been well over a year and I know that many new folks have never seen it before. During this month, I’ll do re-postings of my best educational content because new folks who barely know me never got the chance to read my past posts from 2008/2009. It’s also nice for me to edit the articles to make them slightly better, otherwise known as ’2nd edition posts’. If you read my archives, then it’s simply nice to have a refresher once in a while. I do hope the re-print articles help in some way.

———————————————————————————————————————————

Plutchik’s Wheel of Emotions

As you know by now, psychology is a secondary interest of mine, after reading charts and tarot cards, of course. For this week, I decided to cover the “trader’s mindset” and the most common psychological issues that all traders deal with.

How does someone know that they reached the trader’s mindset? Here are a few characteristics:

1. No anger whatsoever.

2. Confidence and being in control of the self

3. A sense of not forcing the markets

4. An absence of feeling victimized by the markets

5. Trading with money you can afford to risk

6. Trading using a chosen approach or system

7. Not influenced by others

8. Trading is enjoyable

9. Accepting both winning and losing trades equally

10. An open mind approach at all times

11. Equity curve grows as skills improve

12. Constantly learning on a daily basis

13. Consistently aligning trades with the market’s direction

14. Ability to focus on the present reality

15. Taking full responsibility for your actions

Developing the trader’s mindset takes time.

Let’s take 100 traders using the same trading system or approach. It is highly likely that two of them will not trade a system exactly the same way in all aspects. Why is this? Because our mindsets, beliefs, and understandings are unique. It is no surprise that most traders fail and the reason why is because they lack the trader’s mindset.

There are two parts to fixing any psychological problems:

1. Recognizing that it exists

2. Accepting it so you can move on

In trading, this is where it’s so crucial to take responsibility for your own actions because it induces change and you can start making improvements. If you don’t recognize and accept a problem, then you won’t get anywhere!

What are some of these issues that I speak of? Here are a few along with their causes and/or effects (these 15 issues are not meant to perfectly coincide with the above 15 mindset characteristics):

1. Anger over a losing trade – Traders usually feel as if they are victims of the market. This is usually because they either 1) care too much about the trade and/or 2) have unrealistic expectations. They seek approval from the markets, something the markets cannot provide.

2. Trading too much - Traders that do this have some personal need to “conquer” the market. The sole motivation here is greed and about “getting even” with the market. It is impossible to get “even” with the market. Trading too much is also indicative of a lack of discipline and ignoring set rules. This is emotionally-driven.

3. Trading the wrong size – Traders ignore or don’t recognize the risk of each trade or do not understand money management. There is no personal responsibility here. Typically, aggressive position sizes are used, however if risk is not contained, then it could spiral out of control. Usually, this issue comes from traders wanting to make a huge killing. Maybe they do win, but the point is that a bad habit emerges if a trader repeats this behavior.

4. PMSing after the day is over – Traders are on a wild emotional roller coaster that is fueled by a plethora of emotions ranging throughout the spectrum. Focus is taken off of the process and is placed too heavily on the money. These people are very irritable akin to the symptoms of premenstrual syndrome (something I wouldn’t know about personally).

5. Using money you can’t afford to lose – Usually, a trader is pinning his/her last hopes to make money. Traders fear “losing” the “last best opportunity”. Self-discipline is quickly forgotten but the power of greed drives them, usually over a cliff. Here, the rewards are given more attention and overall personal financial risk is ignored.

6. Wishing, hoping, or praying – Do this in church, but leave this out of the market. Traders do not take control of their trades and cannot accept the present reality of what’s happening in the market.

7. Getting high after a huge win – These traders tie their self-worth to their success in the markets or by the value of their account. Usually, these folks have an unrealistic feeling of being “in control” of the markets. A huge loss usually sobers them up pretty quickly. It’s important to maintain emotional restraint after wins, just as you would for losses.

8. Adding to a losing position – Also known as doubling, tripling, quadrupling down, typically, this means that the trader does not want to admit the trade is wrong. The trader’s ego is at stake and #6 comes into effect as the trader is hoping the markets will “work in their favor”. If you are wrong, you have a near 0% chance of making a full recovery.

9. Compulsive trading – Similar to #2, except these traders have an addiction to trading and quite possibly gambling issues. They need to constantly trade, even if there is no rational reason to do so. They are always excited whether they win or lose. These traders will trade in all environments and usually trade when it’s advisable to sit out.

10. Afraid of “pulling the trigger” – This usually means that the trader does not have a system or approach already in place. They have not calculated risk/reward and many times, these trades are unplanned. This also comes after a string of losses. They don’t want to be “wrong again”. There is no trust from within and an obviously lack of confidence.

11. Over-thinking or second guessing – Similar to #10, but these people are usually looking for a “sure thing”, when they clearly don’t exist. Losing is not recognized as a normal part of trading and the risks and unknowns of trading are not fully accepted. These traders cannot make decisions in the face of the unknown.

12. Limiting profits or getting out too early - These traders do not have a plan. There is a direct effect from believing that profits were undeserved…a typical reason for giving them up. Usually a trader is stressed over a trade for some reason and closing the position quickly eliminates the anxiety. Usually, there is a fear of “giving back” those gains.

13. Fear of being stopped out – Traders fear failure and the pain from taking losses is great. Here is another instance where the ego is at risk. They must always be correct or suffer a feeling of “let down”. Don’t forget that your stop loss is your last line of defense.

14. Not following your system – This is a trust and follow-through issue. Perhaps the trader didn’t test it enough, or it recently produced a string of losses, casing some doubt. Your faith in the system is broken. Not only do you not trust the system, you can’t even trust yourself with picking one that works for you. Find and stick with one that is consistent and ‘fits’ with your personality and style.

15. Following other traders (indiscriminately) – These traders do not have a system. They are also limited in trading knowledge. They feel that they will become winners if they simply “follow” someone. These trades are usually impulsive. It’s too dangerous to follow without cause.

The key to all things is creating balance. Remember, it takes time and discipline. The important thing here is to recognize the issues and learn to seriously accept them and take responsibility for your actions. When you finally recognize and accept each of these common pitfalls, you’ll be well on your way to acquiring the trader’s mindset.

utorok 24. augusta 2010

Keynesian End Game – Fooled By Stimulus.

TraderSutra:

Nassim Nicholas Taleb wrote a fabulous book called Fooled By Randomness. It’s a treasured part of my library and will stay so to the day I die. Everyone should read it and then read it again. I won’t go into too much specifics, but it’s all about how investors as well as humans in general often are unaware of the existence of randomness. We tend to explain random events as non-random. Often from this we over analyze and over estimate causality. We tend to make the simple complicated and the complicated simple. When in fact the random happens all of the time and that most are unprepared for it because our belief systems are so out of whack. We have years of ingrown cognitive biases that distort our view of the world and its surroundings.

My point here is not to talk about randomness per say but to talk about being fooled. World markets are currently being fooled into thinking that Keynesianism is going to save us all. In fact, it’s the opposite. Keynesianism will be the hammer to the nail to the coffin to what Neo Classical Economics started. Policy makers and central bankers around the world have been indeed “Fooled By Stimulus.” The idea that exponential increases in debt and leverage will eliminate debt and leverage is at the foremost zeitgeist of Central Bank circles. This one single toxic theme has permeated almost all policy circles. Cheap debt begets more cheap debt. Bankers get drunk off of cheap debt because they can always invest somewhere to gain the spread.

Most central bankers call the Keynesian Theory of Economics the “Beautiful Theory.” This was the most influential economic theory of the early 20th Century. It saved us from the depths of the Great Depression. It is also currently the preeminent theory that is housed today. Keynes was an exceptional thinker who alerted all that financial markets are inherently unstable, Hyman Minsky said similar things in greater detail decades later but it was Keynes who mentioned it first. Keynes also had this Gem, “In the long run we are all dead.” Western democracies needed an approach to balance free market capitalism with government initiatives. Keynesianism was the approach. But all “beautiful” things inherently hide some ugly truths. Like the super model who has an eating disorder, and the gorgeous porn star who comes from a broken home. At the end of the day it all comes out on the wash.

I believe that the Keynesian miracle is dead. The game is over. The stimulus programs have not reduced unemployment and not spurred the real economy. America is currently running two economies and it’s the financial economy that Keynesianism has greatly helped at the expense of the real economy. This is the great divide in our country. It’s not Democrats V. Republicans. That’s too easy. It’s the Have V. Have Not’s. The debt costs used to prop up the financial economy has a direct consequence to the real economy for generations to come.

http://tradersutra.blogspot.com/2010/08/dual-economies-busted-financial-system.html
Keynesian economics was born with the publishing of John Maynard Keynes’ 'The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money.” This theory states or advocates a mixed economy, predominantly driven by the private sector, but with significant intervention by government and the public sector. Keynes argued that private sector decisions often lead to inefficient macroeconomic outcomes, and advocated active public sector policy responses to stabilize output according to the business cycle. Keynesian economics served as the primary economic model from its birth to 1973. It lost some of its luster during the high inflation and subsequent stagflation in the 70’s, but made a comeback during the credit crisis of 2007-2008.

This crisis rejuvenated Keynesian policy and we then received the following from government:
-TARP
-TALF
-American Recovery/Reinvestment Act
-QE
-ZIRP
-Cash For Clunkers
-HAMP

Most of these programs were indeed geared to bailout the financial economy. It had very little effect on stabilizing the real economy but the financial economy just reloaded on the cheap debt.

This type of policy basically makes the point that we can have debt and credit expansion if the economy also grows with it. A rising tide lifts all boats. The rising tide really is a debt tsunami that is going to drown us all. Deflation will be the prevailing theme for developed economies for the foreseeable future. This is why the Fed is obsessed with a busted QE policy. Deflation is poisonous to levered risk assets. What typically happens after we have deflation is mass monetization of bad debt which undoubtedly leads to hyper inflation or general destruction of all Fiat currencies. Hyper inflation is not prices spiraling upwardly out of control, it’s the loss of confidence in ones currency. The Keynesian End Game is total and complete debt monetization which will lead most investors to give up on fiat paper currencies. Any wonder that gold and silver are all in rally mode? What should be happening is debt restructuring and outright default. This would cleanse economies and make lending much more responsible.

The prevailing wisdom of ever expanding debt loads being offset with stronger economies have been around for a long time. It worked all through the 1960’s. The debt loads were high but world economies were just getting in line and economies were able to grow. This made the debt load manageable. Many were worried about corporate debt loads, deficits, and personal debt burdens, but world economies powered higher. The critics were all wrong and looked like idiots.

Statistics on almost all types of debt showed a high correlation between their increases and increases in measures of economic health like the GDP, average personal net worth, and the country’s standard of living. This marched on for decades, but underneath the beauty was a sleeping slug. Over the years, the dollar increase in debt necessary to generate a dollar increase in GDP kept growing. In the late 1940’s and 1950’s, it took about a one dollar increase in debt to generate a one dollar increase in growth, but in each succeeding decade the amount of debt necessary to generate a dollar increase in GDP kept growing. Through the most recent decade, it seems to have taken more than five dollars of debt to produce one dollar of growth, and over the last few years the numbers might have gone into reverse, or perhaps only toward infinity, as all the increase in debt does not seem to create any growth.

Debt used to be the answer but it is increasingly becoming the wrong answer for our current ills. What are the alternatives? Painful ones I presume, that is why that they still alternatives. The easy thing to do is print and monetize debt. The world has not seen a reduction in debt levels since the Great Depression and it is painful obvious that debt reduction is what is needed but will not be implemented until all is lost.

Going back to the correlations of debt and GDP. We see that global GDP especially US Economic growth was 100% credit generated. The 2000-2007 boom was all about residential construction and homeowners using their homes as ATM machines. When the credit boom collapsed, we saw both economic and credit contract. From this policy makers instituted a ZIRP to try and reinflate past bubbles via animal spirits. In the past this worked but presently most Americans are experiencing a balance sheet recession, and no matter where short rates are most are in secular deleveraging mode. Expansionary monetary policy is failing because the debt levels are enormous, as an expansion of credit has lost its power to stimulate growth. As such a reduction in debt levels coupled via restructuring and outright default of debt will have a devastating effect on economic output. What we are experiencing and seeing before our own eyes is the Keynesian End Game. A dead end for Risk Markets .

Just from this logic I can deduce: Forget a double dip recession. The vast amount of Americans never fully recovered from the 2007-2008 credit crisis. A new depression has begun. There will be massive amounts of new debt issued around the world by Central Bankers, this only delays the process of recovery as new debt will not stimulate growth but only keep alive zombie financial institutions. Eventually there is no other option than to restructure/default the debt load. Global debt loads need to shrink and shrink fast. Only after this catharsis where the debt is purged can we can realistically think of growth via reflation.

štvrtok 19. augusta 2010

Be unreasonable - play the uber trade to keep your investment mojo

This article comes from Long Room, part of Financial Times blog Alphaville. I find it bit more bearish than usual stuff, but doesn't Japan have two decades of deflation? Is the debt we accumulated repayable? Answer is obviously yes for the first question and no for the second. But honestly, I still don't know how will the world look in 5 years. And if somebody says he know... don't trust him :)

There is only one investment idea you need to think about right now.  All other investments are for a later date post the appearance of the uber trade.  As this is a singular trade diversification is not useful and could be costly.  You can pick up your various alphas or carry trades (in all its forms...ultimately wealth creation is a carry trade) if you must but know most will be unpicked by the uber trade.  As economics and markets are not fair when panicking even the 'fundamentally good' carry trades will be taken out and shot.
We are  undoubtedly high in the trajectory of the greatest most global leverage bubble ever seen.  As we have lived with this 'profitably' for 14 months post the 'end of the world' (long risk, any risk = bingo) we are complacent about it.  The world is incremental...politicians, consumers, journos, companies, intellectuals and particularly the hallowed markets and their participants (of which I am one)...even Bob Janjuah, Marc Faber, Jeremy Grantham to name but a few 'radicals' are also incrementalists in their insightful contrarian ways...in many ways the incrementalism of the general market participants irritates me most as it has such a deluded perception of its own radicalism and role.  As an aside I point out the ubiquity of data and information increases the weight and momentum of the incrementalist trundle.  (Please note, this is not an anti market polemic as I believe that free and simply regulated markets are awesome and their potential to constantly project the profit motive, or adjust when they realise they have been wrong, is the best system we can have...and we must take the volatility that comes with that as it is completely obvious there isn't a better solution).  It is the meeting of this incrementalism with the POTENTIAL of the uber trade that we should fear.  In some incremental, risk weighted world inhabited by all you very clever market people the uber trade may not be given a certainty of 100%...we could argue about it and give it 'reasonable' weights of say 5-50%...wide margin as its academic and I don't want to argue about reasonable stuff and this is the most stupid time ever to be reasonable
Of course, there is no uncertainty to the uber trade now.  The only uncertainty is when and how it blows.  The reason that there is not uncertainty and there is no scope to be intellectually reasonable is that once the markets sufficiently recognise the not insignificant presence of the uber trade then they will be drawn into pricing it and it becomes an inevitability....no cleverness of economic or monetary management can save us from it.  The stupendous gamma and rapid delta in the realisation finishes the game and makes it 100% certainty.  Its futile, don't argue with me if you think what I say is remotely true then the only options are 0% or 100% at this stage of the game....I know to say this irritates your intellectual prowess and desire to be reasonable/incremental...but get over it quickly as the market thinks quicker than all of us (wisdom of crowds is true)
The uber trade is created by the peak of the leverage mountain and the debt deflation this now heralds.  It may be slow to deflate for a bit...but that will only be as people may be slow to work out the significance of what it means to be on the downward slope...once they catch on incrementalism will turn all helter skelter.  The deeply embedded market and political wish that we can role the debt, even create some more, and then inflate it away is just a fairy tale born of canned historicism, herd thinking (thats after all what similarly educated people do who also enjoy the same ubquitous media feedback) and no little amount of hubris (as we have 1920's style belief in the wisdom of the masters of the market).  What is happening in Europe shows that the myth that debt can be used to grow out of debt bubble has been broken....of course the current inertial momentum of market believes this myth still...however this is one of those delicious schizoid paradox's of the market that happens near momentous times whereby if one could take and isolate each 'opinion former' in the market and ask what they think of this myth you would find a strong majority against.  Accept this and you instantaneously must conclude that credit creation (inc govt) must go into reverse so we have no fuel for the inflation fire (it is not likely - possible imo - that private sector credit appetite and money velocity ignites at this point - if you think otherwise then you should know you are a fantasist and not wise and balanced market operator you perceive yourself to be!).
And here's an alternative take on the 'friendly' inflation delusion.  To have global friendly inflation requires massively co-ordinated policy and action.  It will not come through some miracle of the market.  And it needs to be global and co-ordinated as easily observable and comparative advantages springing from differential experience will create quick and viscous feedback loops (remember we are coming from ridiculous debt level point so room for error is non existent).  Just look at the 1920's experience of reattachment to the gold standard by encumbered economies (much less than today by the way!) and how lack of 'fair play' and co-ordination led to destruction.  Sooooo, it becomes rather simple, without the ability for 'benign' inflationary adjustment the only option is debt deflation and this will destroy some demand so we will experience actual economic deflation
We have no choice to go the old fashioned deflation route out...capital cleansing must occur (and that is another reason why the inflation route is not plausible).  Our wonderful broad based proletarian economies and what we have learned about money (ie gold is sickness and fiat money is useful fantastical stuff) means that we will be able to avoid severe depression...but we will have a depression... particularly China where it will be huge as it has ultimately been the key recipient of the global credit boom in recent years.  The myth of Chinese political and strategic foresight will shown for the nonsense it is.  Yeah, what's happened in China has been quite spectacular and good in many respects...but it is an emerging market command economy where capital has been suboptimally deployed in massive scale.  Its not hard to work out, forget all the specific positives you can say about some elements of Chinese development and just remember that all emerging phases suck in huge amounts of capital (there is always some form of egregious credit creation....the carry trade gone mad even though it was originally rational) and then destroy it - China is no different no matter what GS tells you or all the various cheerleaders on the ground giving expert witness to its realness and greatness - just remember that the vast majority of them are in fact as clueless as you are even if they do get to write intellectual or 'insider informed' pieces in the FT or get to go on CNBC.
So, how do we get out of our deflation? Fortunately it is a naturally process,  wealth is impaired but it survives and once asset values fall sufficiently more than the fall in wealth we get the credit-less lead recovery whereby spontaneous investment begins to take place (good govt  may help support this but shouldn't try to create the process).  Rational greed kicks in.
What's the uber trade?  Long treasuries and dollar, take the debt of some other nations too (hedged) like Germany and UK if you must but really diversification isn't useful.  Hold some cash too particularly in US. Then hold net short position on ALL risk assets...yes, everything!  Particularly gold that most wonderous  of miscalculations!
I am not telling you that I know it is tomorrow.  But I believe that the Europe thing has taken us past the delusional stable equilibrium of the last 14 months and catastrophic instability could come anytime.  Don't be incremental about this!  Remember where the debt level is, remember the 'goodwill' and co-ordination that needs to come to keep us on track for painless inflationary delivery and, probably most of all, remember that we have reached the end of a generational narrative on how the economy and markets work....this lack of narrative to fit what is coming is the intangible catalyst that means markets will take us to the deflationary future no matter what politicians try
Good luck
Your optimistic mojo
PS related to others posts...I think that Germany may be the significant country closest to getting this and that the UK is catching on too.  The US seems furthest from the truth of it and quite hilariously think that it is the rest of the world that is sick and they are healthy!
IMPORTANT NOTICE
This note was brought to you by mojomogoz and Dora the Explorer market educational services, with the aide of FTAlphaville. The authors and sponsors are not responsible for losses arising over 1 second, 1 minute, 1 hour, 1 day, 1 week, 1 month, 1 year, 1 lifetime when readers apply this view. Please note, all market intermediary will seek to screw you.
This service brought to you free of charge. However, donations are accepted and encouraged to 'The Hedge Fund Manager Benevolent Fund' which seeks to retrain and rehabilitate the egos of your very average hedge fund manager

pondelok 9. augusta 2010

QUANTITATIVE EASING: “THE GREATEST MONETARY NON-EVENT”

The Pragmatic Capitalist:

The topic of quantitative easing (QE) has rapidly become the most important discussion in the investment world. As deflation becomes the obvious risk and the economic recovery looks increasingly weak investors are again looking to the Fed to save their skin from a Japan style deflationary recession. The irony here is so thick you could choke on it, however, like some sort of sick masochist, investors continue to return to the trough of the Federal Reserve so they can gorge on half-truths and misguided policy responses.

There is perhaps, no greater misunderstanding in the investment world today than the topic of quantitative easing. After all, it sounds so fancy, strange and complex. But in reality, it is quite a simple operation. JJ Lando a bond trader at Goldman Sachs has eloquently described QE:

“In QE, aside from its usual record keeping activities, the Fed converts overnight reserves into treasuries, forcing the private sector out of its savings and into cash. This is just a large-scale version of the coupon-passes it needed to do all along. Again, they force people out of treasuries and into cash and reserves.”

Some investors prefer to call it “money printing” or “stimulative monetary policy”. Both are misleading and the latter is particularly misleading in the current market environment. First of all, the Fed doesn’t actually “print” anything when it initiates its QE policy. The Fed simply electronically swaps an asset with the private sector. In most cases it swaps deposits with an interest bearing asset. They’re not “printing money” or dropping money from helicopters as many economists and pundits would have you believe. It is merely an asset swap.

The theory behind QE is that the Fed can reduce interest rates via asset purchases (which supposedly creates demand for debt) while also strengthening the bank balance sheet (which entices them to lend). Unfortunately, we’ve lived thru this scenario before and history shows us that neither is actually true. Banks are never reserve constrained and a private sector that is deeply indebted will not likely be enticed to borrow regardless of the rate of interest. On the reserve argument the BIS explains in great detail why an increase in reserves will not increase borrowing:

“In fact, the level of reserves hardly figures in banks’ lending decisions. The amount of credit outstanding is determined by banks’ willingness to supply loans, based on perceived risk-return trade-offs, and by the demand for those loans.

The aggregate availability of bank reserves does not constrain the expansion directly. The reason is simple: as explained in Section I, under scheme 1 – by far the most common – in order to avoid extreme volatility in the interest rate, central banks supply reserves as demanded by the system. From this perspective, a reserve requirement, depending on its remuneration, affects the cost of intermediation and that of loans, but does not constrain credit expansion quantitatively.

The main exogenous constraint on the expansion of credit is minimum capital requirements. By the same token, under scheme 2, an expansion of reserves in excess of any requirement does not give banks more resources to expand lending. It only changes the composition of liquid assets of the banking system. Given the very high substitutability between bank reserves and other government assets held for liquidity purposes, the impact can be marginal at best. This is true in both normal and also in stress conditions. Importantly, excess reserves do not represent idle resources nor should they be viewed as somehow undesired by banks (again, recall that our notion of excess refers to holdings above minimum requirements). When the opportunity cost of excess reserves is zero, either because they are remunerated at the policy rate or the latter reaches the zero lower bound, they simply represent a form of liquid asset for banks.”

The most glaring example of failed QE is in Japan in 2001. Richard Koo refers to this event as the “greatest monetary non-event”. In his book, The Holy Grail of Macroeconomics, Koo confirms what the BIS states above:

“In reality, however, borrowers – not lenders, as argued by academic economists – were the primary bottleneck in Japan’s Great Recession. If there were many willing borrowers and few able lenders, the Bank of Japan, as the ultimate supplier of funds, would indeed have to do something. But when there are no borrowers the bank is powerless.”

In the same piece cited above, the BIS also uses the example of Japan to illustrate the weakness of QE. The following chart (Figure 1) shows that QE does not stimulate borrowing (and the history of continued economic weakness in Japan is coincidental):

“A striking recent illustration of the tenuous link between excess reserves and bank lending is the experience during the Bank of Japan’s “quantitative easing” policy in 2001-2006. Despite significant expansions in excess reserve balances, and the associated increase in base money, during the zero-interest rate policy, lending in the Japanese banking system did not increase robustly.”

qe11 QUANTITATIVE EASING: THE GREATEST MONETARY NON EVENT


(Figure 1)

Koo goes a step further in describing the failure of QE to promote private sector recovery. His simple example is one I have used often:

“The central bank’s implementation of QE at a time of zero interest rates was similar to a shopkeeper who, unable to sell more than 100 apples a day at $100 each, tries stocking the shelves with 1,000 apples, and when that has no effect, adds another 1,000. As long as the price remains the same, there is no reason consumer behavior should change–sales will remain stuck at about 100 even if the shopkeeper puts 3,000 apples on display. This is essentially the story of QE, which not only failed to bring about economic recovery, but also failed to stop asset prices from falling well into 2003.”

Koo continues by emphasizing how ineffective monetary policy is during a balance sheet recession:

“Even though QE failed to produce the expected results, the belief that monetary policy is always effective persists among economists in Japan and elsewhere. To these economists, QE did not fail: it simply was not tried hard enough. According to this view, if boosting excess reserves of commercial banks to $25 trillion has no effect, then we should try injecting $50 trillion, or $100 trillion”

After years of placing more apples on the shelves the Bank of Japan finally admitted that the policy had been a failure:

“QE’s effect on raising aggregate demand and prices was often limited” (Ugai, 2006)

That all sounds too eerily familiar, doesn’t it? No, no – Mr. Bernanke hasn’t failed. He just hasn’t tried hard enough….But perhaps the reader believes Japan is different and not applicable. This is a reasonable objection. So why don’t we look at the evidence from the last round of QE here in the USA. Since Ben Bernanke initiated his great monetarist gaffe in 2008 there has been almost no sign of a sustainable private sector recovery. Mr. Bernanke’s new form of trickle down economics has surely fixed the banking sector (or at least bought some time), but the recovery ended there. It did not spread to Main Street. We would not even be having this discussion if we were in the midst of a private sector recovery. The surest evidence, however, is in the Fed’s own data. We can also look at the Fed’s recent Z1 to show that households remain hesitant to borrow (see Figure 2). Friday’s consumer credit data was yet another sign of contracting consumer credit and a lack of demand for borrowing. Despite the Fed’s already failed attempt at QE (see Figure 3) we are convinced that Mr. Bernanke just needs to throw a few more apples on the shelves. The historical evidence is clear – QE will do little to stimulate borrowing and help generate a private sector recovery.

qe2 QUANTITATIVE EASING: THE GREATEST MONETARY NON EVENT


(Figure 2)

qe3 QUANTITATIVE EASING: THE GREATEST MONETARY NON EVENT


(Figure 3)

In addition, there is one great irony in all of this misunderstanding. The hyperventilating hyperinflationists and those investors calling for inevitable US default are now clinging to this QE story as their inflation or default thesis crumbles before their very eyes. The new hyperinflationist theme has become a story of “if this, then this, then THIS!” – the ludicrous 3 step investment thesis that the economy will become so fragile that the government will pile on with more stimulus, which will worsen matters and force them to stimulate further which will then result in hyperinflation and/or default. Most investors have enough trouble predicting what the next event will be – connecting the dots two or three steps down the line is not only ill-advised, but is hardly even worthy of consideration….Let’s just call a spade a spade – the inflationistas have been wrong and the USA defaultistas have been horribly wrong.

What is equally interesting (in addition to the fact that QE is not economically stimulative) with regards to this whole debate is that this policy response in time of a balance sheet recession is not actually inflationary at all. With the government merely swapping assets they are not actually “printing” any new money. In fact, the government is now essentially stealing interest bearing assets from the private sector and replacing them with deposits. This might have made some sense when the credit markets were frozen and bank balance sheets were thought to be largely insolvent, but now that the banks are flush with excess reserves this policy response would in fact be deflationary - not inflationary. Why would we remove interest bearing assets from the private sector and replace them with deposits when history clearly shows that this will not stimulate borrowing?

All of this misconception has the market in a frenzy. Portfolio managers and day traders can’t wait to snatch up stocks on every dip in anticipation of what they believe is an equivalent to the March 9th 2009 low that was cemented by government intervention. As I have long predicted Ben & Co. have failed. If there is one thing that we know for certain over the last 24 months it is that Mr. Bernanke’s monetary policy has done very little to get the private sector back on its feet. This man failed to predict the crisis (was in fact oblivious to its potential), initiated the wrong trickle down policy response and yet now we turn to him to save us from a double dip and his Committee responds with more discussion of QE? Will we ever learn?

In describing the negligence of such monetary policy Richard Koo uses the analogy of a doctor who simply tells his patient to take more of the same medicine he originally prescribed:

“At the risk of belabouring the obvious, imagine a patient in the hospital who takes a drug prescribed by her doctor, but does not react as the doctor expected and, more importantly, does not get better. When she reports back to the doctor, he tells her to double the dosage. But this does not help either. So he orders her to take four times, eight times, and finally a hundred times the original dosage. All to no avail. Under these circumstances, any normal human being would come to the conclusion that the doctor’s original diagnosis was wrong, and that the patient suffered from a different disease. But today’s macroeconomics assumes that private sector firms are maximizing profits at all times, meaning that given a low enough interest rate, they should be willing to borrow money to invest.. In reality, however, borrowers – not lenders, as argued by academic economists – were the primary bottleneck in Japan’s Great Recession.”

Dr. Bernanke has misdiagnosed this illness one too many times. At what point does someone tell him to put the scalpel down and step away from the table before he does even greater harm?

References

BIS (2009) http://www.bis.org/publ/work292.pdf

Koo, R (2009) The Holy Grail of Macro Economics

Ugai, H (2006) Effects of the Quantitative Easing Policy: A Survey of Empirical Analyses. Bank of Japan Working Paper Series no 6-E-10

nedeľa 1. augusta 2010

štvrtok 29. júla 2010

Deleveraging and balance sheet recession

Richard Koo has a nice article in The Economist about balance sheet recession. He has there very interesting point:
The private sector will not be responding to the talk of inflation or inflation targeting because it is responding to the fall in asset prices, not consumer prices.
In times of deleveraging households are repaying their debt and they do everything to minimize borrowings. But if the value of their debt is too high, it becomes impossible to repay it. So the only choice is default. This chart summarize it nicely. Too bad I don't know the source of it.

The gap between the the value of debt and value of properties is too large and without asset prices inflation it cannot be solved. So the only way for FED is to inflate and print money...

Original article from Koo is worth reading:

Is America facing an increase in structural unemployment? No, America lacks the necessary commitment to stimulus.
THERE is no reason for structural unemployment to increase following an ordinary recession or financial crisis. However, the US today is suffering from a balance sheet recession, a very rare ailment which happens only after the bursting of a nationwide debt-financed asset price bubble. In this type of recession, the private sector is minimising debt instead of maximising profits because the collapse in asset prices left its balance sheets in a serious state of excess liability and in urgent need of repair. When the private sector is deleveraging even with zero interest rates, the economy enters a deflationary spiral as it loses aggregate demand equal to the sum of unborrowed savings and debt-repayments every year. If left unattended, the economy will continue to contract until either private sector balance sheets are repaired, or the private sector has become too poor to save any money (=depression). The last time this deflationary spiral was allowed to materialise was during the Great Depression in the US.
In this type of recession, monetary policy is largely useless because people with balance sheets underwater are not interested in increasing borrowings at any interest rate.  There will not be many lenders to those with impaired balance sheets either, especially if the lenders themselves have balance sheet problems. The private sector will not be responding to the talk of inflation or inflation targeting because it is responding to the fall in asset prices, not consumer prices. The money supply also contracts when the private sector de-levers because bank deposits, the largest component of money supply, shrinks when the private sector draws down its deposits to pay back its debt. During the Great Depression, the US money supply contracted 30% mostly for this reason.
Since the government cannot tell the private sector NOT to repair its balance sheets, the only thing the government can do to keep the economy going is for the government to borrow and spend the unborrowed savings in the private sector and put them back into the economy’s income stream. In other words, fiscal stimulus becomes indispensible in a balance sheet recession. Moreover, the stimulus must be maintained until private sector deleveraging is over.
The problem is that in a democracy, it is extremely difficult to maintain fiscal stimulus during peacetime. As can be seen in the US, UK and in so many democracies around the world today, the demand for fiscal consolidation overwhelms the policy debate once the initial fiscal stimulus manages to stabilise the economy. Not realising the critical danger posed by private sector deleveraging at zero interest rates, those who push for fiscal consolidation argue that a big government is a bad government and that the wasteful deficit is jeopardising the future of our children and grand-children. 
When the deficit hawks manage to remove the fiscal stimulus while the private sector is still deleveraging, the economy collapses and re-enters the deflationary spiral. That weakness, in turn, prompts another fiscal stimulus, only to see it removed again by the deficit hawks once the economy stabilises. This unfortunate cycle can go on for years if the experience of post-1990 Japan is any guide. The net result is that the economy remains in the doldrums for years, and many unemployed workers will never find jobs in what appears to be structural unemployment even though there is nothing structural about their predicament. Japan took 15 years to come out of its balance sheet recession because of this unfortunate cycle where the necessary medicine was applied only intermittently. 
The real impediment to a sustained recovery from a balance sheet recession therefore is the inability of orthodox academics and policy makers to accept the fact that the private sector is minimising debt and that their aversion to fiscal stimulus based on the assumption that the private sector is maximising profits is unwarranted. If Japan had known that it had actually contracted a different disease and kept its fiscal stimulus in place until the private sector balance sheets are repaired, it would have recovered from the recession much faster and at a much lower cost than the 460 trillion yen or $5 trillion it eventually took to cure the disease.