piatok 19. februára 2010

Think Greece Is Scary? Now Get Ready For Spain

Business Insider: "
Spain has been under increasing pressure about its own sovereign debt position as dark clouds continue to swirl around its Mediterranean neighbor Greece. Their debt is huge, the banking system is troubled, and they had a monster housing bubble. Strictly speaking, the country may not be as bad as Greece, but when you consider how enormous Spain is, its troubles could make Greece look like child's play. Just consider this: Spain's GDP is $1.6 trillion. Greece's is $357 billion.


1. Property Boom: Spain experienced a property boom larger than the US and UK



Property Boom: Spain experienced a property boom larger than the US and UK
Source: The Economist

This property boom saw the price of Spanish real estate rise 80% from 1990 to 2009.
This was due to similar reasons as those for the US and UK booms: relatively low interest rates and an easy credit environment.





2. Property Boom: Boom leads to employment growth and influx of workers

Property Boom: Boom leads to employment growth and influx of workers
Source: http://www.indexmundi.com/g/g.aspx?v=72&c=sp&l=en
The property boom led to a period of relatively low unemployment in Spain and an influx of foreign workers and dependents from abroad.
Since the boom collapsed, this influx has only served to furtherexacerbate the unemployment problem.
Source: Index Mundi





3. Unemployment: 18.8%



Unemployment: 18.8%
Source: Instituto National de Estadistica
Spain's unemployment was a staggering 18.8% in the fourth quarter of 2009. This is a rise on the previous quarter's 17.9% and was above the consensus projections by 0.3%.
This is a return to the pre-boom time numbers, though higher than the year 2000 average of 16%.
Source: Instituto Nacional Estadistica



4. Unemployment: Increase looks set to continue to trend upward



Unemployment: Increase looks set to continue to trend upward
Source: http://www.indexmundi.com/g/g.aspx?v=72&c=sp&l=en
Unemployment looks continue to trend upwards due to an increasing labor force and new austerity measures which will cut down on government spending.
The austerity budget is calling for a 5% cut in GDP and whileillegal immigrant worker numbers are decreasing, it appears unlikely the rate will be equal by any measure.
Source: Index Mundi



5. Euro Zone Imbalances: Inability to deal with labor problems



Euro Zone Imbalances: Inability to deal with labor problems
Source: OECD
Because of Spain's position in the Euro zone, it has been confronted with wage demands which are unfit for its less modern economy.
Spain cannot compete with Germany for the quality of its manufactured goods, as it cannot devalue its currency, lower wages, and become more competitive in the market place.
Source: OECD



6. Debt: During the boom times, it seemed as though Spain was doing well at paying down debt.



Debt: During the boom times, it seemed as though Spain was doing well at paying down debt.
Source: Index Mundi
Spain, unlike Greece, used its period of growth to pay off debts and only had debt of 55% of GDP, which is the Euro zone average, prior to the crisis.
This should, theoretically, make servicing its debt easier as it has less.
Source: Index Mundi


7. Pension And Entitlement Schemes: Slash and Burn

Pension And Entitlement Schemes: Slash and Burn
Source: OECD
Spain has been on a slash and burn assault of entitlement programs since the severity of its recession became obvious.
Most obvious of these cuts is the raising of the retirement age to 67 from 65. This, coupled with cuts in the civil service, could make a strong impact on the country's deficit.
Source: OECD





8. No Growth Sectors In The Economy: GDP unlikely to grow swiftly



No Growth Sectors In The Economy: GDP unlikely to grow swiftly
Source: Banca de Espana
The collapse of the property bubble has put Spain in a position of retrenchment in terms of where it sees its economy going.
It now needs to develop new growth sectors to grow its GDP. Likely candidates include energy, where Spain has invested heavily in solar technologies.
Source: Banco de Espana



9. Who is exposed: Financial Companies



Who is exposed: Financial Companies
Source: BIS
Compared to Greece, foreign bank exposure to Spanish government debt is limited. This does not mean that it isn't systemically large in certain countries banking sectors, however.
A primary example of this would be Cathay Life Insurance of Taiwan, which has significant exposure to Spanish debt. More interesting is which banks and or insurance companies have issued derivative instruments on Spanish debt, such as CDS.
These investors could be put under heavy pressure come July, when Spain has huge obligations to meet.
Source: Bank of International Settlements



10. Right now, Spain looks in good shape in debt markets



Right now, Spain looks in good shape in debt markets
Source: Reuters
Spain is still in a position much better than the other PIIGS states. It does not have their debt load, nor the CDS spread of its rivals.
However, contagion via a European default or a prolonging of the Greek debt crisis could bring further pressure on the Spanish economy, which will result in higher CDS spreads and increasing yields on debt.
This week will see another Spanish debt issuance, this time of the 15-year variety, which will provide raw data on how markets perceive the country against its neighbors. Future months might hold more problems for Spain, however.
Source: Reuters



11. But July is D-Day for Spanish debt



But July is D-Day for Spanish debt
Source: Barclays Capital via FT Alphaville
Barclays Capital finds that Spain is not one of the PIIGS most in need of debt refinancing over the next several months, but will be faced with huge obligations in July, according to the FT Alphaville.
Spain may be safe from the uncertainty over Greece right now, but come July things could get extremely difficult.
Approximately 25 billion Euros ($34.31 billion) in refinancing are needed in July, and Spain will have to tap the debt markets to get that. Spain can only hope the crisis over Greece is over by then, lest it might be dealing with its own.



Financial Time's blog Money-supply today writes, that not only july, but next two years will be interesting:


Spain faces $200bn maturing debt



A troubling chart from Thomson Reuters this morning, showing Spain facing $203.7bn maturing syndicated debt in the coming six years. That is roughly a fifthof the country’s annual gross domestic product (which was $261.5m for Q4 last year). Italy is second with $95.9bn over the same period. Greece - orange on the chart - is almost insignificant in context.

Chart courtesy of Thomson Reuters; source Thomson Reuters LPC/DealScan
Maturing loans are significant as new debt will be needed to plug the gap. Countries perceived as risky will pay a higher ‘new issue premium’, as a mooted deal in Greece is currently showing. Two questions: who will be these countries’ creditor (China?)? And what are the figures for the UK & US (I’m working on this one)?



UPDATE


Upper graph shows maturing corporate debt, not sovereign. You can see volume of sovereign debt here... It looks like Italy is the king here.



štvrtok 18. februára 2010

High frequency trading in 10 seconds

High frequency trading has became very popular topic recently thanks to Zero Hedge. I saw couple weeks ago a video, where a HFT trader Manjo Narang explains how it works. When a strategy has 52% probability of be right, you can transfer it to be profitable not by making a million dollar bet on it, but you can make a million bets with one dollar. Because of law of big number, you win 520.000 times and loose 480 000 times for a net gain of 40.000 dollars... How easy :)
Yesterday in Financial Times article by Jeremy Grant and Michael Mackenzie I saw this chart, which explains how HFT trading affects the markets. Average number of trades per day is rising, but average shares per trade is falling.




I'm sure readers are aware, that HFT is skewing the market and can be dangerous. We saw it in Rambus (RMBS) shares recently.



Anyway, video is really interesting and you can watch it here and read article here.

streda 17. februára 2010

Presenting Total Bank Assets As A Percentage Of Host Countries' GDP

Zero Hedge: "

With the threat of sovereign default and contagion now pervasive within the Eurozone periphery, it is relevant to quantify the relative exposure of various banking centers' assets as a percentage of host countries' total GDP. The reason for this is that in Europe for many countries a sovereign default would not have as great an impact, as a risk-flaring contagion impacting these countries' primary financial entities, whose assets account in some cases for multiples of host GDP. For example in Switzerland, the assets of the top two banks, UBS and Credit Suisse, alone account for nearly 600% of the country's GDP. And while Switzerland is relatively isolated from the budget and deficit crises in the PIIGS and STUPIDs, other countries such as Italy, Belgium and ultimately France, Germany and the UK, are much more exposed.

  • Belgium - Dexia: 180%of GDP
  • France - BNP Paribas, Credit Agricole, SocGen: 237% of GDP
  • Germany - Deutsche Bank: 84%
  • Italy - Unicredit, Intesa Sanpaolo: 101%
  • Netherlands - Fortis: 155%
  • Spain - Banco Santander: 92%
  • UK - RBS, Barclays, HSBC: 337%

Compare that to the top 5 banks in the US (a list which excludes hedge funds such as Goldman Sachs).

  • US - JP Morgan, Citigroup, Bank of America, Wells Fargo and Fannie: just 56% of GDP.

The question which pundits should be focusing on is once the Greek crisis flares up and takes down several peripheral non-hosted banks, just what the interplay of a 'falling domino' scenario will be not only on neighboring European countries, but also on the holdings of their domestic banks. Because it is inevitable that the same kind of bank run witness in Greece, will become a pervasive phenomenon and impact Portugal, Spain, Italy, etc, which would be the precursor to a global bank run.

The chart below demonstrates graphically the ratio between a given bank's asset and the GDP of its host country. Unfortunately for Europe, there is a dramatic concentration of bank assets precisely in some of the most precarious regions. Which is why Germany may have kicked the can down the road for at least a month, but the issue will come back with a vengeance for the simple reason we have noted from the start of this crisis: only Bernanke has a money printer. Everyone else actually has to produce 'stuff', sell it and collect taxes if they want to fill catastrophic budget deficits. And the latter, as we have seen, is something the developed world has been horrible at doing over the past decade, courtesy of the Goldman-facilitated innovation explosion.

A European Slowdown Would Only Nick the US

From Morgan Stanley:

Limited spillover to the US. The European sovereign debt crisis may net to slower European growth from an already-tepid starting point. Although the European Council of government leaders has pledged "to take determined and coordinated action, if needed, to safeguard financial stability in the euro area as a whole", that backstop is unlikely to immunize the euro-zone economies completely. The crisis likely will tighten financial conditions and promote fiscal austerity, consisting of increased taxes and lower public sector demand. And the crisis hits a still-tender euro area economy, which we have expected to advance just 1.2% in 2010. Incoming data showing that growth rose just 0.1% in 4Q09 and a poor start to 1Q10 underscore the downside risks (see Whither Greece? January 25, 2010; and European Economics Chartbook: Expanding at a Pedestrian Pace - Ripples at the Periphery, February 1, 2010).

The impact of even dramatically slower growth in Europe would only trim US growth fractionally; Asia is far more important for the US outlook (see Global Economics: Asian Amplification, February 4, 2010). However, the European sovereign crisis does create a tail risk for US growth and markets: If the crisis spills over into broader risk-aversion and a drying up of liquidity - the functional equivalent of the US subprime crisis - the consequences could be more dire. At the least, these unknown risks make us more cautious about risky assets (see Sovereign Crisis Roadmap, February 11, 2010).

Challenge to sustainable growth. Strong growth abroad is one of four pillars for our view that the US economy is at the start of sustainable growth through 2011 (the other three: improving financial conditions, persistent impact from fiscal stimulus, and the elimination of excesses (see Outlook 2010: Higher Rates, Fed Exit and Sustainable Growth, January 4, 2010). Thus, a slowdown in Europe's economies would at least challenge that thesis.

Indeed, from a short-to-medium-term cyclical perspective, the crisis seems likely to slow European growth through three channels: 1) rising risk premiums on the region's sovereign debt will tighten financial conditions; 2) higher funding costs and constraints on market access will limit the supply of bank credit; and 3) fiscal tightening - both spending cuts and tax increases - will weigh on growth in peripheral economies. In turn, the willingness of core EU countries to backstop the periphery, perhaps with an emergency lending facility sponsored by Germany, seems likely to cause the contagion to spread to the core. As a result, we now expect 10-year Bund yields, which have begun to rise despite soft incoming European data, to rise to 4.5% this year. A weaker euro will be a partial offset by helping boost the region's export competitiveness; we expect the euro to decline to 1.24 EUR/USD.

Quantifying the fallout for the US. We estimate that a one-percentage-point slowdown in European growth might shave 0.2% from that in the US. Three channels matter: exports, earnings and financial linkages.

Exports: Big share, but slow growth. Exports of goods and services to the European Union account for 29% of the US total, but given our outlook for tepid EU growth, the contribution to US growth from European demand is small. Nonetheless, a dramatic slowdown in European demand would dent US export growth. In contrast, Asia ex Japan is growing eight times faster than the EU, and Canada and Latin America are growing four times faster. The share of US exports of goods and services to Asia (27%) is comparable to the EU, while Canada and Latin America account for 37%. We see upside risks to both those sources of export vigor.

Earnings/Income: An important, overlooked channel. US income from direct investment is much more closely coupled to Europe, because Europe accounts for 57% of the US$3.1 trillion in overseas facilities owned by US companies. So, a slowdown in European growth will affect results at US affiliates in the region, which contribute roughly one-sixth of US earnings. Slower growth in Europe would slice 200-300bp from the likely rise in US earnings this year. Fortunately, the growth differentials matter; while Asia accounts for only 20% of direct investment income, its rapid growth is contributing a like amount to US earnings growth.

Financial linkages to Europe: More diffuse and hard to calibrate, but could be noticeable. A rise in core European sovereign yields could intensify concerns about the sustainability of US fiscal policy among global investors and push up US Treasury yields. Uncertainty about the slowdown in Europe might weigh on US credit and equity prices. Slower growth in Europe would depress results at US global financial services firms and could make them more hesitant to lend. US financial exposure to Europe is relatively low: For example, US banks' claims on residents of the European periphery were a miniscule 0.3% of total assets as of 3Q09, and claims on all European residents amounted to only to 4.6% of total assets (see Betsy Graseck's Quick Comment: International Exposure a Low Risk for US Banks, February 10, 2010). As we learned in the financial crisis, however, such linkages could be the most important of all if idiosyncratic risk morphs into something systemic. Indeed, while the retreat in risky assets in the past few weeks is not yet a headwind for growth, it is hardly a plus (for credit implications, see Problematic Relatives - Downgrading € IG Credit, February 12, 2010).

Cross checking. To cross-check these results, we estimated a Vector Auto Regression among three variables: Growth in US GDP, US domestic demand, and overseas GDP. Shocking the system with an impulse response shows that a 1pp change in the growth of foreign GDP will move US GDP growth by 60% of that, which is consistent with our back-of-the-envelope calculation of a 0.2% impact from a similar change in Europe alone.

Contagion tail risk. Our base case is that peripheral Europe will muddle through with assistance from the core. Yet the crisis will surely slow European growth somewhat. Contagion spreading from the European banking system is the biggest tail risk. If the crisis spills over into broader risk-aversion, a drying up of liquidity, and deleveraging - the functional equivalent of the US subprime crisis - the consequences could be more dire. That scenario is far from investors' minds, and we think it is highly unlikely, given that EU officials have made it clear that conditional assistance for Greece is coming. But that's what makes it important to think about.


Leadership Lessons from Dancing Guy

Derek Sivers:



Transcript:

If you've learned a lot about leadership and making a movement, then let's watch a movement happen, start to finish, in under 3 minutes, and dissect some lessons:

A leader needs the guts to stand alone and look ridiculous. But what he's doing is so simple, it's almost instructional. This is key. You must be easy to follow!

Now comes the first follower with a crucial role: he publicly shows everyone how to follow. Notice the leader embraces him as an equal, so it's not about the leader anymore - it's about them, plural. Notice he's calling to his friends to join in. It takes guts to be a first follower! You stand out and brave ridicule, yourself. Being a first follower is an under-appreciated form of leadership. The first follower transforms a lone nut into a leader. If the leader is the flint, the first follower is the spark that makes the fire.

The 2nd follower is a turning point: it's proof the first has done well. Now it's not a lone nut, and it's not two nuts. Three is a crowd and a crowd is news.

A movement must be public. Make sure outsiders see more than just the leader. Everyone needs to see the followers, because new followers emulate followers - not the leader.

Now here come 2 more, then 3 more. Now we've got momentum. This is the tipping point! Now we've got a movement!

As more people jump in, it's no longer risky. If they were on the fence before, there's no reason not to join now. They won't be ridiculed, they won't stand out, and they will be part of the in-crowd, if they hurry. Over the next minute you'll see the rest who prefer to be part of the crowd, because eventually they'd be ridiculed for not joining.

And ladies and gentlemen that is how a movement is made! Let's recap what we learned:

If you are a version of the shirtless dancing guy, all alone, remember the importance of nurturing your first few followers as equals, making everything clearly about the movement, not you.

Be public. Be easy to follow!

But the biggest lesson here - did you catch it?

Leadership is over-glorified.

Yes it started with the shirtless guy, and he'll get all the credit, but you saw what really happened:

It was the first follower that transformed a lone nut into a leader.

There is no movement without the first follower.

We're told we all need to be leaders, but that would be really ineffective.

The best way to make a movement, if you really care, is to courageously follow and show others how to follow.

When you find a lone nut doing something great, have the guts to be the first person to stand up and join in.

China Pulls the Plug on U.S. Treasuries

George Washington's Blog: "

You've heard that:

Senior Chinese military officers have proposed that their country ... possibly sell some U.S. bonds to punish Washington for its latest round of arms sales to Taiwan.
You know that China is dumping American assets, unless backed by the government.

Now, the U.S. is reporting that:

Foreign demand for U.S. Treasury securities fell by the largest amount on record in December with China reducing its holdings by $34.2 billion.

The December drop in treasury holdings pre-dates the recent spat over Taiwan, and is therefore unrelated. However, it does show that China is starting to give up on our 'too big to fail' nation (and see this).

And bond auctions are now starting to fail.

Total foreign holdings of U.S. treasuries fell by $53 billion. Japan has now passed China as the largest foreign holder of treasuries."


Today FT Alphaville continues:


A good day for China conspiracy theorists, a bad one for holders of US Treasuries, as official US figures confirmed that earlier paranoia about Beijing’s plans to dump Treasuries were proven correct.

From Wednesday’s FT:

Foreign demand for US Treasury securities fell by a record amount in December as China purged some of its holdings of government debt, the US Treasury department said on Tuesday.

China sold $34.2bn in US Treasury securities during the month… leaving Japan as the biggest holder of US government debt with $768.8bn. China overtook Japan as the largest holder in September 2008.

Not only that. The overall monthly sell-off of $53bn worth of Treasuries was the biggest on record. Net purchases of long-term US securities declined to $63.3bn from $126.4bn in November, according to the Treasury figures.

However, foreigners overall increased their purchases of US equities, buying $20.1bn in December after buying $9.7bn the previous month. Japan’s holdings for example rose 1.5 per cent in December to $768.8bn, while China’s dropped 4.3 per cent to $755.4bn.

And also China bought $4.6bn of longer-dated coupon debt.

The overall shift away from short-dated Treasuries, amid growing concerns about the US fiscal deficit but more importantly a move away from the “flight to safety” strategy of the last couple of years, could mean the US will have to pay more to service its debt interest and put further downward pressure on stock prices.

Indeed, as Associated Press notes on Wednesday: economists are split over the significance of the decline. Some doubt that the drop in foreign holdings of short-term Treasuries signifies growing unease about holding US debt, noting that net purchases of longer-term Treasury debt rose in December by $70bn.

But others see the decline as a warning signal, adds AP:

They fear that foreigners, especially the Chinese, have begun to worry about record-high US budget deficits and are looking to diversify their holdings. A sustained drop in foreign demand for dollar-denominated assets could lead to higher US interest rates and falling stock prices [and] could threaten the US recovery. But economists said they see no such evidence yet.

For China, the shedding of US debt marks a reversal that it began signalling last year by suggesting it may reduce some of its holdings – and also signifies a big turnround from earlier in 2009 when senior Chinese officials highlighted their frustrations at having to maintain large holdings of US Treasuries.

Alan Ruskin, a strategist at RBS Securities, told the FT that China’s behaviour showed that it felt “saturated” with Treasury paper and that the December sale signalled a trend.

For the US, such a trend would be very unwelcome, coming as the White House grapples with cutting the US deficit, which is projected to be $1,560bn in 2010, or 10.6 per cent of GDP.

Alan Meltzer, an economics professor at Carnegie Mellon University, said China’s shift should be a wake-up call for Washington, according to AP.

“The Chinese are worried that we have unsustainable debt levels, and we do not have a policy for dealing with it,” Meltzer said.

From Beijing’s perspective, though, it’s a very tricky balancing act. China still has substantial holdings of US Treasuries and a further sign of no-confidence from Bejing could drive down the value of its US securities portfolio.

China’s Treasury holdings peaked at $801.5bn in May, and net sales in November and December were the first consecutive months of reductions since late 2007, reportsBloomberg.

But, as Minyanville’s Howard Simons notes:

The marginal supply of investable funds in the world today is China’s $2.4 trillion stash of foreign reserves. Where they invest those funds, for how long they peg the yuan at its present rate near 6.83 per dollar, and their own internal credit policies are the dog; everyone else right now is the tail, and what a wonderful view that is.

Some economists have warned against reading too much into December’s drop in foreign purchases of short-term Treasury debt, pointing to month to month volatility in the figures, as AP notes. They also argue that Europe’s debt crisis has put pressure on the euro and boosted demand for US Treasuries and the US dollar.

But, as ShortView’s Michael Mackenzie points out on Wednesday, the big question at a time of unease about sovereign debt, is what happens if China continues on this path?

At some point, foreign indigestion of Treasuries means the US will need domestic investors to step up and buy and at the risk of higher rates, he warns, concluding:

While bond traders dismiss Tic data as old news, it is perhaps worth recalling that “a trend is your friend” only when you are on the right side of it.


utorok 16. februára 2010

The Sick Men of Europe: the challenges of a monetary union in middle age

This is really good report from JP Morgan about possible outcomes of Greece debacle. HT Zero Hedge.


It might seem odd that Greece is surfacing questions about European public debt and the sustainability of the European Union. After all, Greece is only 2% of EU GDP. But what’s in play here is an idea: can a region with very different economic and cultural characteristics form a durable monetary union? Bear Stearns was only 2% of broker-dealers and capital markets banks, but its failure set in motion the end of a different idea: that very highly leveraged entities could own risky, illiquid assets and rely on wholesale funding rather than more stable customer deposits. We must explore as investors whether the end of an idea is dawning in Europe. The point here is not to engage in idle speculation, but to consider the un-thinkable, something that has been very worthwhile to do over the last decade in markets history.

This is not the first time concerns on the Euro have surfaced. Milton Friedman and Martin Feldstein both questioned its viability years ago. In the following pages, some background, charts on the current state of affairs and some thoughts on what happens next. Irrespective of whatever subsidies may be extended to Greece, this problem will be hard to resolve. Implications for European government bonds, the Euro and equity markets are substantial.

The Euro’s predecessor: the failure of the ERM
The creation of the Euro came on the heels of a prior attempt at achieving monetary stability in Europe, the European Exchange Rate Mechanism (“ERM”). Member countries had independent central banks, but currencies had to float within pre-specified bands. The ERM virtually collapsed in 1992, since tighter monetary policy that suited Germany at the time was too painful for countries like the U.K. (which suffered from a recession and 10%+ unemployment), as well as Italy, Spain and Portugal. The bands of the ERM were widened in 1993 to the point that these currencies effectively became floating again.

The Euro is born: Der Würfel ist gefallen
Even before the ERM collapse, the idea of a more durable currency union was put in motion. Member countries would yield monetary policy decisions to a Central Bank, and adhere to tight budget deficit criteria. But according to people like Bernard Connolly (see box), the die was cast when member countries were allowed to join the Euro at possibly elevated exchange rates, despite divergent economic circumstances, productivity and income levels. As shown below, the currencies of Greece, Italy, Portugal, Spain, and Ireland (the “GIPSI” countries) fell sharply in the aftermath of the ERM failure, and then stabilized when the contours of the European Monetary Union (“EMU”) were put in place. Note how the Irish Pound and Italian Lira actually rallied during the era of Euro convergence (1996-1997).


Allowing other countries into the Euro at elevated exchange rates was seen as a win-win situation at the time, since this would increase the purchasing power of savings held by GIPSI citizens; and for Germany, as the region's industrial export power, it created a large "captive" group of wealthy consumers of German goods. [Note the similarities to the circumstances around German unification: some East German savings were converted to Deutsche marks at a rate of 1.8 M to 1 DM, vastly exceeding the real value of the East German mark. This sowed the seeds of the 1992 German inflation/ERM crisis.]

The problem with this conversion: it set the European Union on a course in which GIPSI countries would consume a lot, but not produce much, as their workers would be too expensive to hire. This would eventually prove to be a Faustian bargain for Germany, as they are now expected to mitigate the recession’s impact and subsidize debt burdens of member countries.

Were initial currency conversion rates too high? The evidence says Oui / Si / Jå / Sim / Ne

How can one tell if the initial currency conversion rates were too high? If the GIPSI countries remained competitive with Germany, then the answer would be no. However, the evidence suggests that right off the bat, the GIPSI countries started losing ground. I will spare you the economic jargon, but “real effective exchange rates” from the OECD and the EU Commission are two measures of relative competitiveness. When a line in either chart is rising, that country is losing competitiveness relative to the countries below them. The charts tell the story here.




Despite losing ground in terms of competitiveness, the GIPSI countries went on a consumption boom, fueled by lower interest rates set by the ECB, and funded by external capital4. As shown below (left), consumption took off in Italy, Spain and Portugal (Greece’s numbers are off the chart). Another look, in the chart at the right: GIPSI countries all ran sizable trade imbalances relative to Germany, highlighting the “captive consumer” connection between Germany and the GIPSI countries.

The recession hits and the party ends

The onset of the first global consumer recession in 17 years now puts Friedman/Feldstein concerns to the test. With the collapse in economic activity, GIPSI budget deficits are soaring, since governments have been forced to provide fiscal stimulus to offset sharp increases in unemployment and business failures. What makes the crisis worse is that Europe does not have a lot of ammunition; some member countries have consistently run budget deficits and debt/GDP ratios in excess of what was agreed in the EU Stability and Growth Pact. Even with all the temporary stimulus, the Eurozone looks to have grown at 0% in Q4 2009. Unlike the U.S. and Japan, European industrial production and retail sales have still not bounced from the bottom. Prompted by Greece’s challenges with rolling over its debt, concerns about broader GIPSI public debt burdens are rising, as demonstrated by the increasing cost of default protection in the CDS markets.




The Greek “adjustment”
Few market participants believe Greece will be able to carry out the fiscal adjustment it proposes. Greece plans to make one of the largest fiscal contractions on record, around 10% of GDP over 3 years, without any clear incentives or penalties for not achieving their goals, and is a country with a history of failed fiscal consolidations in the past. Strikes announced so far: tax officials, doctors, teachers, civil servants, etc. Euro area policymakers have stated that Greece won’t be expelled, won’t be allowed to default, and that the IMF won’t be invited in to help (yet). Greece is looking to borrow another EUR 50 billion in 2010, after having borrowed EUR 8 bn in January.


The United States of Europe?
Will the European Union bail out its most profligate member in Greece? It won’t be easy to explain to EU citizens. Greece revised its 2009 budget deficit to be 3x prior releases, prompting Swedish ministers to describe the data as “fraudulent”. Greece has the lowest ranking in the EU on Transparency International’s Corruption Perceptions Index, and has the largest underground “shadow” economy in the entire OECD (see chart), creating endemic problems with taxation and economic efficiency.


The crisis takes on broader implications as well: it has surfaced support for a more powerful federalist government in Europe. EU President Van Rompuy proposed giving the EU more "economic governance" powers in the aftermath of the recession, perhaps without explicit agreement from national delegations. More direct calls for a pan-European government with powers of economic enforcement, bond issuance and civilian deployment come from Guy Verhofstadt, President of ALDE (the 3rd largest group in the European Parliament) and author of “United States of Europe”.

Within Germany, the Finance Ministry appears to be against a bail-out5, while the Foreign Ministry appears to be for it. Germany will be interesting to watch: Angela Merkel is the first Chancellor born after WWII. Her predecessors (Kohl, Schmidt, Schroder) were less able to assert German nationalism; the same is not the case for Merkel and Finance Minister Schaeuble. A 2009 poll shows 70% of Germans opposed to bailing out Ireland or Greece6; they are joined by Otmar Issing (former Chief Economist at the ECB), Karl Otto Pohl (former President of the Bundesbank) and Current ECB Chief Economist Jürgen Stark.


Now what?
It looks like there will be an immediate effort by EU members to stave off contagion and a broader debt crisis, and provide some loans and debt guarantees to Greece. More details to follow next week. But as we’ve seen in the past, such solutions can be temporary if underlying structural conditions don’t change. Here’s a brief synopsis of the 5 options in play:

[1] Deflation. European currency devaluations date back to 11th century England, when they were used to raise silver to pay off raiding Viking invaders. But when a country loses its ability to devalue its currency, there’s only one option left when facing a loss of competitiveness: sharp declines in goods prices, wages and real estate. Hong Kong in 1998 is an example: the U.S. dollar anchored was so restrictive, that real estate prices fell 50% to restore some equilibrium. Can Europe handle declining wages/prices and persistently high unemployment, economically or politically? So far, there have been some austerity measures announced in Spain and Ireland. Portugal is trying, but the current government does not have a majority in Parliament.
* Ireland: Reduced public sector wages (from the highest levels in the EU), spending cuts and tax increases
* Spain: 10% replacement rate on retiring public sector workers, spending cuts, labor unions agree to 1%-2.5% wage hikes
* Portugal (proposed): public sector wage freeze, reduction of public sector employees and sales of government investments If these steps succeed, it would represent a political and economic validation of the concept of a monetary union in Europe.

[2] A large decline in the value of the Euro. A further decline could help countries like Ireland. But for the Euro to fall enough to help countries like Greece and Spain, it would have to fall much more (perhaps below parity with the U.S. dollar), since their economies are more closed (see chart on trade to GDP), and require a bigger change in the terms of trade. Such a low level on the Euro might create inflationary issues for Germany, and we all know how they feel about that.

[3] Regional subsidies. Bond guarantees are easy to provide, until they need to be funded. There are also EU infrastructure funds, bilateral country loans and IMF loans that can be provided to Greece. There are pages of EU treaties which prohibit bailouts, but in practice, they can be circumvented.

[4] Default but remain in the EMU. Countries like Greece would default and effect a Brady-bond solution: debt forgiveness combined with an austerity plan to put it back on a sustainable path. But in Europe, banks own cross-holdings in member country sovereign debt (e.g., French banks owning Greek bonds). An unpleasant outcome, economically and politically. Fun Fact: France defaulted on its debts 8 times between 1500 and 1800; Spain did it 13 times.

[5] A country leaves the EMU. A sovereign could leave, devalue by 30% and denominate its government bonds in the new currency. But legions of lawyers have analyzed the consequences for private sector companies (with assets that can be seized in other countries), and don’t know the answer. Germany could also withdraw and allow the rest of the EMU to find a sustainable currency level. It would result in a Full Employment Act for derivatives lawyers. This would be the nuclear option; unlikely.


INVESTMENT IMPLICATIONS

The European Union is a political concept 50 years in the making, and one that benefits from substantial support from many of its citizens. It would be premature in the life cycle of the EMU, now in its middle age, to succumb to a debt crisis in its periphery. The voices calling for greater European economic and political integration may win out, taking a line from Obama advisor Rahm Emanuel: “never let a serious crisis go to waste”.

However, if GIPSI public sector debt burdens are not addressed, we may be right back here later this year or next. It pays to consider the pricing of credit risk in those infrequent situations that end badly for bondholders: Argentina (2001), Russia (1998), Conseco (2002), Parmalat (2003) and the 2008-2009 crop (CIT Group, Lehman Brothers, GM, Washington Mutual, etc.). In each case, there were interim periods when stop-gaps were put in place, rescue financing from the IMF or interested governments and white knight companies was just around the corner, analysts declared the crisis over, bond prices rallied for a while, and everyone took a sigh of relief. But it was only temporary.

We wrote in December 2009 that we believed that the dollar’s decline vs. the Euro was over; that we are overweight U.S. equities vs. European equities; that we pulled in our OECD bond durations; and that we are generally taking less risk in portfolios than normal at a time of rebounding global corporate profits and manufacturing. None of these positions has changed, and are reinforced by the latest round of uncertainty coming from the European Union.

Michael Cembalest
Chief Investment Officer
JP Morgan Private Banking



What about the United States as an example of a monetary union that can survive severe recessions?

There are substantial differences between the United States as a monetary union and the EMU. There are three worth highlighting:

Higher labor mobility in the U.S. At a meeting in Spain in La Coruna in 2007, I asked a client why his idle workers would not move to Frankfurt where there were job opportunities. His reply: “Frankfurt? They would not even move to Barcelona”. Compared to Europeans, U.S. citizens are 10 times more likely to move in response to unemployment differentials, and 2 times more likely to move in response to wage differentials. [Source: “The European Immobility Puzzle and the Role of Migration Costs", Michèle Belot, University of Essex, European Commission "Employment in Europe" conference].

Borrowing constraints on U.S. States. Unlike European member states, U.S. states generally adhere to balanced budget policies. With the onset of the recession, U.S. states needed a substantial transfer from the Federal government ($180 bn) to prevent large tax hikes and spending cuts. But at least the starting point for most U.S. states is closer to balanced, unlike European member states.

Higher U.S. tolerance for regional subsidies. The U.S. is much more accustomed to the kind of regional subsidies that the EU is now debating. Fiscal transfers in the United States eliminate as much as 40 percent of a decline in regional income, while fiscal transfers between EU member states are only a tiny fraction of that amount. [Sources: Xavier Salai-Martin and Jeff Sachs, “Federal Fiscal Policy and Optimum Areas”; Barry Eichengreen, “One Money for Europe? Lessons from the U.S. Currency Union.”; and “The United States as a Monetary Union and the Euro, a Historical Perspective”, Michael D. Bordo, Cato Journal, Spring/Summer 2004].



2-11-10 - EOTM - Sick Men of Europe (3)